Skip to main content

Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory

- Why Should I Care?

Politicians spend your money. You might want to understand what their arguments are for increasing expenditures, or changing tax rates. Hint: most of their arguments come from Keynes’ macroeconomic theory.

CASE SPEECH WRITER

- This Lecture Has 8 Parts

  • Sorting Out the Variables
  • The Keynesian Cross
  • Unemployment and Equilibrium
  • Shifts in AE
  • Limitations
  • Solving for Equilibrium
  • The Government Multiplier
  • Principles

- What is a Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory?

There are dozens of macroeconomic theories, but they all stem from the models inspired by J. M. Keynes’ famous theory about aggregate demand (published in 1934). We will present here the basic ideas of the macroeconomic model known as the “Keynesian Cross.” This model was first drawn not by Keynes, but by Paul Samuelson and William Nordhaus in 1948. John Hicks is widely credited with the first graphical version, now called IS-LM, in 1937.

It's main objective is to find a level of aggregate production that is an equilibrium of aggregate demand, and aggregate income. If this level of aggregate economic activity is insufficient to create employment for everyone in society, the model offers an argument for government intervention to step in and provide stimulus to the economy. Hence, Keynesian economics provides a rationale for interventionism.

This argument contradicts the widely-held view at the time (1930's), that there would always be enough demand to justify a level of supply. This principle is called Say's Law, and was formulated by French economist Jean-Baptiste Say in 1803. The basic idea is actually hard to translate to English. It is called the ''Loi des débouchés'', which in English means other avenues, or market opportunities. Say wrote that the production of a good, generates the opportunity to purchase other goods. Over time, the principle was used to understand the general equilibrium between aggregate demand and aggregate supply of goods and services. The principle also states that supply generates demand, and so it is associated to pro-industry views.

The Keynesian view does not contradict Say's Law directly, it adds that this equilibrium of demand and supply may be insufficient to provide enough employment for the population. The Keynesian view was a full-frontal attack on classical laissez-faire economics, whose lack of reaction to the suffering of people during the Great Depression (1929-1939) prompted Keynes to argue for government intervention.

  • Sorting Out the Variables

First of all, we must identify the variables in the model, and associate each to a role. This will help us sort out the relationships between the variables and how they will be used in the model, which, I remind you, is a simulation of what the economy could really be like. Keynes’ basic idea was that the level of production in the economy does not always match a situation of equilibrium between the aggregate level of spending in the economy, and the aggregate level of income. According to Keynes there can be a situation of entrenched unemployment.

This being said, Aggregate Expenditure should equal Aggregate Income. The model is about flows. It explicitly identifies the factors that compose Aggregate Expenditure.

AE = Consumer spending + Government spending + Investment spending

AE = C + G + I

Keynesians do not define the income side with much detail. The important aspect is that the equilibrium output level must be the equation of Y (Aggregate Income), and AE.

At equilibrium, we have:

Y = AE

Also, the model does not discuss price levels in relation to AE. We will take price levels to be fixed. In this model, the dependent variable is Y, the level of production. All of the other variables are independent, such as income, expenditure, and any environmental variables such as productivity, technology, demographics, etc.

The independent variables are divided into two categories: endogenous (effects predicted by the model), and exogenous (prior cause). Income is an endogenous variable. It responds to AE.

AE is an endogenous variable, defined as the sum of C, G, and I.

C is assumed to have an autonomous level of expenditure which is not related to income levels. However, it will also rise with income.

G, and I are assumed to be fixed, and unrelated to income.

What all of this means is that our level of production depends on spending. But if consumer spending does not equal income, the system will be out of balance. The model illustrates situations when spending does not match income, which results in entrenched unemployment.

  • The Keynesian Cross

The first thing you need to draw is what everyone calls the 45 degree line. This curve represents all the levels of production at equilibrium, where AE = Y. This line is used as a benchmark. The AE = Y curve is infinite, as we are discussing a scenario where labour is not scarce. The model is designed to discuss situations when at least some resources are idle, indefinitely, such as an economic depression. The model is not designed to discuss overproduction, which is a major environmental issue we should discuss later.

The next thing you need to draw is the AE curve, which is the sum of C, G, and I. This one is trickier.

First, we assume that spending will never be zero, even if income is zero. Why? The model assumes that a society can use savings, or loans, to consume at a minimal level to avoid starvation and death. This is called the autonomous level of expenditure. By the way, this is exactly what happened during the COVID-19 pandemic, when many people used savings to continue paying for rent and groceries. The government used public debt to help those who lost income and had no savings.

So let’s scale and set autonomous expenditure at 400 billion dollars, on the AE axis (vertical).

The next step is to add in the induced expenditures. This spending is a function of income. As income rises, we spend more. For each dollar of added income, AE will rise. But. There are savings.

We won’t spend the whole dollar of extra income. If our savings rate is 20 percent, we will spend 80 cents on the dollar. Because of savings, the slope of the AE curve cannot be as steep as the 45 degree curve.

For example, the marginal propensity to consume can be 80%.

MPC = 0.8

Since the MPC is the slope of the curve, and that the slope is smaller than 1, but greater than 0, the two curves will therefore cross. This cross-point represents the equilibrium level of production. Macroeconomic equilibrium is maintained by a simple feedback mechanism: inventories. If you choose a point on the AE curve which is inferior to Y, this represents a situation where inventories sit on the shelves. This prompts suppliers to reduce production, the coordinate on the AE curve achieves the level where Y = AE.

When AE is superior to Y, inventories are depleted. This prompts suppliers to increase production, until Y = AE. The inventory feedback may explain small and short-lived recessions. These situations are temporary and will return to normal. Hence, the Keynesian model does allow for free markets to self-regulate if the difference between production and aggregate expenditure are not great.

Also, at equilibrium, I = S. If not at equilibrium, the difference between AE and Y gives you the level of dissaving, or saving, where S is smaller or larger than I. This aspect of the model can be explained in more detail in more advanced texts.

Graph - Finding the equilibrium output level using the Keynesian Cross (B$)

image-1654275517769.png

As you can see on the graph, the equilibrium level is given at Y = 2000 B$, or 2.0 trillion dollars. This is roughly the size of the Canadian economy. Notice the scales of the Y axis, and the AE axis are identical. This is on purpose. The equilibrium coordinate (2000, 2000) forms a perfectly square box, hence the 45 degree angle of the Y = AE curve.

  • Unemployment and Equilibrium

Unemployment may exist even if the system is in equilibrium. This statement put Keynes at odds with the Classical school of thought, epitomized by Adam Smith, and later Jean-Baptiste Say. According to Say's Law, employment income is always sufficient to purchase all of the production in the economy.

Keynes argued that during a recession, or worse a depression, sometimes planned production is larger than sales. Capitalists and industrialists can mistakenly estimate consumer demand. Let's say workers have been paid to make automobiles, but only 90 percent of output has been sold in that year. Management has to reduce planned output by more than the 10 percent missing, because they need to sell the overstock before they can bring production levels back to regular levels. This mismatch between planned output and planned expenditures is not accounted for in classical economics.

To establish this on the graph, you have to identify the production level associated to full-employment (Yf). You then compare that level of production with the equilibrium level of production (Ye).

If Yf > Ye , then you have an under-production output gap

If Yf < Ye , then you have an over-production output gap.

This aspect of the model is referred to Entrenched Unemployment. This concept is associated to deeper and long-lived recessions, the worse of which are called depressions. In these cases, the simple inventory feedback will be insufficient. The output gap is much larger, and is due to a drop in autonomous (planned) expenditures. When this is the case, government intervention is argued for by Keynesian economists.

The graph below shows a situation where the red circle represents Ye . The green star represents Yf, the desired level of output to achieve full employment. If you look at the AE axis, you will notice the difference is 400 billion dollars.

Graph - Visualizing Entrenched Unemployment

image-1654276259201.png

The solution to generate more employment, is to stimulate the economy using government expenditure.

  • Shifts in AE

The problem with the economy is that it may be producing below potential. So what to do? Before Keynes, most people would say, “let the markets figure this out.” As the Great Depression dragged along, Keynes felt the government should act.

This is where the exogenous variables come into play. Fear of the future, low expectations of wage increases, pessimism, and all sorts of feelings people have during a recession will act as a negative shock on the economy, dragging down C, and I.

Also, an increase in the savings rate will reduce the slope of the AE curve (Advanced level).

If a downward shift in AE is caused by a decrease in autonomous expenditures, then you might have a situation where unemployment is high, and companies are not increasing their investments because there are not enough projects to invest in, in the first place. As AE drops, so does the equilibrium level of income.

If there are no outside forces to change this situation, the equilibrium production level has shifted down. Unless unemployed people die, or migrate, this is a problem of idle resources.

For classical economists, this was nonsense. But during the Great Depression, it was real-life, true story. This is where Keynesians argue the government should get involved. By increasing its autonomous expenditures, through infrastructure programs, military purchases, or anything else, the AE curve will climb back up, and equilibrium production will grow again.

GRAPH: An increase in G, ceteris paribus, to increase AE.

image-1654276905090.png

As you can see on the graph, an 80 billion dollar stimulus package was sufficient to solve a 400 billion dollar gap in output. This is because the money does not sit, people spend it. And since they save at a 20 percent rate, we can assume they spend 80 percent of stimulus money. That means the money will cycle 5 times in the economy, so that 80 billion dollars of stimulus is multiplied into 400 billion dollars of output. We will explain this in more detail.

  • Limitations

There are important limitations to this model. First of all, its aim is very limited: to depict the effect of a drop in aggregate expenditure on overall production levels, and employment. The model does not factor in any kind of explanation of economic growth in the long-run. Austrian economists have argued it does not factor in the role of the private sector, which can invent new products, open new opportunities to invest.

Second, it does not factor in the role of prices, or inflation. When prices drop during a recession, people can buy more stuff with the same income. The model assumes constant prices.

Third, the model assumes rich people have the same savings level as poor people. As income rises, the savings rate should increase. But the model assumes a constant level of savings.

Fourth, the model makes no account of a “supply-shock”, for example if resources are limited by a strike, war, or a natural disaster. The model was created to show how government intervention can multiply GDP when the economy is under-producing. It does not deal with any suppliers, or the problems they may have in meeting aggregate demand. In the wake of the COVID-19 pandemic, the world economy was subject to a supply-side shock and this model is not of much use for that.

Fifth, the model is obsessed with the savings rate, which determines consumer spending. This is encourage people to save less, during a recession, shifting focus away from productive investment in risky ventures that increase productivity, and towards focusing only on increasing consumption. More houses and more cars will not help build a more productive, and prosperous, economy in the future. More of the same is expansionary, but it is not economic development.

  • Solving for Equilibrium

AE is given by expenditures C, I, G.

AE = C+ I + G

AE also includes induced expenditures which are a function of aggregate income: MPC*Income.

AE = (C + MPC*Income) + I + G

Which is the same as writing

AE = C + I + G + MPC*Income

At Equilibrium,

AEe = Income

therefore, we can write 

Incomee = C + I + G + MPC*Incomee

If the autonomous expenditures and MPC are known, then we can solve for the equilibrium income level.

  • The Government Multiplier

Keynes argues the government does not need to fill the entire production gap with fresh spending. Because money circulates several times in the economy, a relatively small injection of funds can fill the gap.

The government multiplier is a ratio of how many times the extra government money can turn into GDP-Income.

GM = (New equilibrium Income – Previous equilibrium Income) / Government Injection

Since the new production level depends on the MPC, the multiplier depends on how much people save, vs. consume, their extra income. This equation is the inverse of the MPS, which is equal to 1-MPC.

In other words: the autonomous spending, or any addition to autonomous spending, should be considered as the FIRST ROUND of spending in an economy. When someone’s spending becomes someone else’s income, then there is a SECOND ROUND of spending.

The number of rounds depends on the MPC, that is, the share of earned income that will be spent on product. The multiplier basically tells you the number of rounds. If MPC is 0.8, you will have 5 rounds of spending for each additional autonomous dollar. This means that a 20 B$ stimulus (extra G), will generate five times that amount in terms of GDP at the end of the year, or 100B$.

Here is the math,

 GM = 1 / ( 1 - MPC )

The multiplier allows us to calculate the level of government intervention needed to fill in an output gap.

∆Y = ∆G * GM

Where ∆Y = Output gap, or the difference between Potential Real GDP and actual levels of Real GDP.

For example, if MPC = 0.8, then GM = 5. In this case, an output gap of 100 B$ would be solved by an added 20 B$.

∆Y = ∆G * GM
100 B$ = ∆G * 5
∆G  = 100 B$ / 5 = 20 B$

  • Principles

Positive:
There is an equilibrium level of production that matches aggregate income and aggregate spending. Too much savings can create a disequilibrium in production levels.
It is possible to see a stable equilibrium level of production associated to a large and stable output gap, and associated surplus of labour (unemployment).

Normative:
Government should intervene if the output gap, and its associated labour surplus is too large.

- Wrap-Up

A macroeconomic theory is a set of assumptions and logical deductions that help us predict outcomes in the economy.

The AE model is based on Keynes’ description of Aggregate Expenditure.

Positive shifts of AE create jobs, negative shifts AE create unemployment. In this case, government should increase expenditures to compensate and bring production levels back to equilibrium.

- Cheat Sheet with Memory Helper

Aggregate Expenditure:
A curve that represents autonomous levels of spending, and induced spending which rises with income.

45 degree curve:
A curve that represents all levels of production for which Say's Law is respected, that spending equals income.

Government Multiplier:
A calculation of the multiplier effect of added government spending on GDP, based on the marginal propensity to consume.

- References and Further Reading

Hicks, J. R. (1937). Mr. Keynes and the "Classics"; A Suggested Interpretation. Econometrica. Vol. 5, No. 2, pp. 147-159 (13 pages). https://www.jstor.org/stable/1907242

James, E., Wellman, S. J. & Aberra, W. (2010). Macroeconomics, 2nd ed. Pearson Canada. Chapter 9.

Keynes, J. M. (1936). The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. London: Palgrave Macmillan.

Samuelson, P. A. & Nordhaus, W. D. (2004). Economics, 18th edition. McGraw-Hill/Irwin. Originally published in 1948.

Say, J.-B. (1803). Traité d'économie politique.

Stiglitz, J. E. & Walsh, C. E. (2006). Economics, 4th Edition. New York City: W.W. Norton.