Marshall's Supply and Demand
- Why Should I Care?
How can you make predictions about the future? Markets are subject to complex environments, with a multiplicity of actors, and even more shocks coming in from all sorts of random directions. There is a way to sort through the chaos.
- This Lecture Has 4 Parts
- Assumptions about price arbitrage
- Assumptions about buyers and sellers
- Types of industrial structure
- Dealing with outside forces
- What is Marshall’s Supply and Demand?
British economist Alfred Marshall wrote the book on markets in the early 20th century. His work has become the foundation for micro-economics to this day. The supply and demand model aims to capture a whole industry, rather than individual transactions. That means that the model Marshall put together has to impose a single price on all of the buyers, and all of the sellers. To make this model work, there are a few assumptions that need to be made about the actors involved.
An interesting aspect of the model is that if you change some of the assumptions, especially about sellers, you change the type of industry structure. In the case where a seller has extreme power over the market, we call this a monopoly and Marshall’s model allows us to predict what will most likely happen to prices and quantities offered in that situation.
- Assumptions about price arbitrage
Marshall assumes that all of the product will be sold at the same price, no matter who buys it, or how much they purchase. This is a pretty strong assumption, because in real life, sometimes people negotiate, and sometimes it helps to get a better price, when you buy a larger quantity.
Marshall, like Walras, was trying to build a model using mathematics, which was a new and cutting-edge thing to do in the early 1900’s. It would be a little bit more difficult to model an industry where all sorts of contracts could be negotiated at different prices. That’s not to say it does not happen in real life. Some industries function this way. Sometimes long-held relationships allow for preferential pricing. Sometimes volume gets a rebate. Sometimes timing makes a difference. Real life has a way of being full of quirks.
The point of a model, however, is to run simulations based on logic. In this case, quirks can get in the way, so economists prefer simplifying assumptions. In this model, there is a single price for every transaction, and if you must know, it is imposed by a binding disinterested arbiter. Also, the model assumes that prices determine the behaviour of buyers and sellers on the market. In other words, quantities demanded, and quantities supplied, are both a function of the product’s price.
- Assumptions about buyers and sellers
The supply and demand model assumes that buyers and sellers will do what’s in their best interest. For example, buyers will purchase more product if it becomes less expensive. The model also assumes that sellers will supply more product if its price increases.
These assumptions of rational behaviour are the object of much debate in economics, whereas some see the assumptions as being quite strong statements about how people should act, rather than depict how people actually behave in reality. Arguments over rationality tend be quite heated, really (see Goodman et. al., chapter 4 for a recent discussion of contributions from behavioural economists). Try to explain to a dog lover, that pets are not a rational choice.
Nonetheless, the model needs these assumptions to hold true. Because these behaviours are consistently going in opposite directions, both price, and production levels have to stabilize. We will explain this in more detail later.
- Types of industrial structure
The supply and demand model allows the economist to analyze scenarios where sellers have more or less power on the market.
For example, if there is only one seller, we call this industrial structure a Monopoly. In this case, you can imagine the seller will increase prices to maximize their profits. For consumers, this is not the best situation. It is also not the best solution for other suppliers because they are excluded from the market.
Ideally, the industrial structure that provides the most product, at the best price, is called Perfect Competition. In this case there are lots of sellers, and lots of buyers, and the price is as fair as possible.
- Dealing with outside forces
The model’s main strength is not so much that it predicts a stable price, an equilibrium, but that it allows analysts to deal with changes coming from outside forces. The model allows you to sort all of the variables that could affect the economy, or an industry in particular, and predict the ripple effects of an outside shock on the market.
Some of these shocks can be political, like the election of a new government which brings new types of regulations. Other shocks can be from related markets, such as inputs, or specialized services. Whatever the shock, the model helps to make a smart prediction.
- Cheat Sheet
Quantity supplied
A quantity of product that is supplied by sellers.
Quantity demanded
A quantity of product that is demanded by buyers.
Industrial Structure
The type of industry depending on the level of competition.
- References and Further Reading
Goodwin, N., Harris, J. M., Nelson, J. A., Rajkarnikar, P. J., Roach, B., & Torras, M. (2018). Microeconomics in Context, 4th Edition. Routledge.
Marshall, A. (1890). Principles of Economics.