Skip to main content

The Costs of Production

- Why Should I Care?

Compare clean water and diamonds, which is more expensive? Which is more important? Understanding the meaning of value, and how prices are set, may unlock the often-frustrating mysteries of market prices.

- This Lecture Has 4 Parts

  • Accounting Costs
  • Opportunity Costs
  • Production Possibilities
  • Positive and Normative Principles

- What are the Costs of Production?

The price of a final product includes all the costs associated to its production. These are Accounting Costs. Obviously, if the costs increase, so too will the price of that product. A basic law of business is that it is very difficult to sell a product below its accounting cost price.

But there is more to the story than these costs. Economists insist economic choices must be taken into consideration. Most people have to make choices, so when they do, they sacrifice one option for another. These Opportunity Costs tell us the true reasons we choose to produce/consume one thing rather than another.

  • Accounting Costs

The final price of a good or service must include all the costs associated to its production. These are also called “cost-price”, or “accounting” costs.

For example, the price of an iPhone must cover the cost of raw materials (land) such as minerals, plastics and electronics, as well as the labour entailed in assembling and delivering the product, which incur more land distribution costs associated to travel and retail outlets. On top of that, the price of an iPhone must also cover the cost of machinery, buildings and intellectual property (physical and human capital).

Finally, the price also covers a profit margin (entrepreneurship) for those who designed, organized production, paid the transportation costs, etc., which in this case is Apple, Inc.

Consider that a final product is worth more than the initial value of the raw materials. Each new resource, each modification, each part assembled to the whole, and each transformation adds value to the previous product. This idea is called “Added Value”.

Buyers are also usually willing to pay more for transformed products that are more useful. Producers can charge extra for “some” profits because organizing production adds value to the set of resources. Would you prefer to live in a house that is assembled and functional, or in a tent next to a container filled with building materials you need to assemble? The house, you would prefer the convenience of a turn-key home, rather than months of assembly!

All in all, valuable products tend be expensive. But there are important exceptions. Prices don’t necessarily reflect the social value of an object. This is a paradox many economists have written about. For example, a 1 gram diamond (5 carat) is worth more than the same weight or volume of water. In fact it is worth more than 40,000 $.

But water is more important to our well-being than diamonds. Same goes for air, food, shelter, and clothes. In my opinion, societies tend to do better when the important things of life are free, or very much affordable.

  • Opportunity Cost

For most people, the cost of producing something is measured by the cost of the resources used to make the good or service. However, economists insist on including the cost of what is given up, when we choose to produce something. The idea of this hidden cost is present in human thought since time immemorial, but was formalized in 1914 by the Austrian economist von Wieser.

For example, economists compare the cost of making iPhones, with the cost of using those resources to make something completely different, like tomatoes. If you buy an iPhone worth 500 dollars, you have to realize you also gave up 1,000 tomatoes.

Economists insist on measuring this “opportunity cost” of what we give up when we choose to produce something else. The opportunity cost is the next best alternative sacrificed when making a choice.

Say you have to give up two months of eating premium ice-cream to buy one pair of shoes. The Opportunity Cost of the shoes is X tubs of ice-cream.

This concept is important because there are more costs to doing something, than the sum of the cost of the resources used to make that item.

Another example: if the government builds a hospital for 5 billion dollars, it has no money left to build hockey rinks. So the cost of the hospital is not just 5 billion dollars, it’s also the absence of a cultural infrastructure.

  • Production Possibilities

Individuals have to choose what to buy, because they have a budget limit and they can’t buy everything they want. Well, so do societies. We can use an economic model to understand this situation. The origin of this model is not clearly cited in most textbooks. A 1941 paper by Stolper and Samuelson regards the model as being well-known under the names of 'substitution curve', 'production indifference', or 'transformation curve'. The PPF model is widely known as a building block of the Austrian School of Thought, which contributed notably the concept of opportunity cost. Many credit Haberler with the first rendition of the PPF, in an article written in German in 1930 (Lerner, 1932).

Model – Production Possibilities Frontier

  1. Definitions
    1. Maximum production of Good A is set on the vertical axis.
    2. Good B is set on the horizontal axis.
    3. The curve represents maximum production levels according to different combinations of goods A and B.
  1. Assumptions
    1. An economy produces only two goods.
    2. All the workers can work on any of the two goods, but only one at a time.
    3. There are no economies of scale.
    4. Workers are not equally productive at making each good.
  1. Hypotheses
    1. The maximum production level is shown on the Production Possibility Frontier (PPF).
  1. Predictions
    1. The PPF is concave.
    2. The economy will produce more if it diversifies.

Graph - The Production Possibilities Frontier

image-1652136039522.png

LABEL AXIS !

Interpretation

Points on the graph represent a combination of production in good A, and good B. Any point above the PPF curve represents a combination which is impossible to produce. Any point below the curve is possible to produce. In this case resources go idle, most importantly labour. This type of unemployment and underemployment is a complicated issue.

Also, economists believe that, in general, the curve is not a straight line. Why? Because they believe that workers are not the same, they have specialties. If you assume that workers don't share the same expertise, the same skills, and the same competencies, then some workers are more productive than others. The result is that the system is optimized when it produces a variety of goods. This works if you assign work according to people’s strengths. If you allocate the productive workers to their best industry, obviously, the systems becomes more efficient. In other words: division of labour according to workers’ specialties generates higher overall production. This is why some economists believe the system would produce more goods and services if you strike a balance in the quantity of different goods to produce.

Also, it is interesting to note that the slope of the PPF curve represents the opportunity cost of adding one unit of Good B. The more specialized the economy in Good B, the higher the loss of Good A. Economists call this the Law of Increasing Opportunity Costs.

Finally, it is possible for the whole curve to shift outwards, if there is an increase in productivity, or an increase in available resources. If this increase only affects one sector, the shift will only affect the intercept of that sector. Inversely, if capacity deteriorates, the curve would shift inwards.

Given this principle, if a society wishes to expand its economy overall, it should invest massively in productive endeavors, such as improving physical and human capital. In this case, the whole curve would shift outwards.

  • Principles

Positive:
There is an opportunity cost to shifting production from one industry/sector to another.

Normative:
Economies should aim to produce at capacity, so as to avoid leaving resources idle.
Economies should aim to produce a variety of goods to maximize both utility of consumption, and productivity of diverse labour resources.

Green Policy

The biggest ecological problem created by our economy is that we are polluting the natural environment, and the clean-up costs are either ignored or left to younger generations to bear. These clean-up costs are usually unaccounted for in the market price of a product.

However, there is a way to measure the true cost of producing, and disposing, of product. This is called Life-Cycle Cost, which we obtain from using a Life-Cycle Analysis. If you had to pay the full cost for waste clean-up, or recycling, of everything you purchase, you might make drastically different decisions as a consumer!

The Green Playbook is fairly clear on this issue. Environmental debts are just as costly as financial debts. They must be paid back. And better yet, it’s always better not to contract any debts at all in the first place. Imagine the money we would save if we did not have to clean up our own messes.

The other thing industrial lobbies forget to mention is that the opportunity cost of not having a planet to live on is incalculable. There is no other option. So whatever the cost of cleaning up rivers, ponds, streams, wetlands, lakes, abandoned gas stations, and old mining sites (there are hundreds in Quebec alone), it’s worth it.

If that argument is insufficient, one may also add the accounting cost of modern life. Trees provide clean air, cooling, fruits, teas, and building materials at a very low cost, compared to oxygen tanks, air conditioning machines, imported produce and foods, and producted materials like plastics and metals. Modern life is quite expensive!

Imagine how much accounting costs could be saved by large cities if they did not have to clean the water that runs to your home.

Climate Change Solution

The problem with Climate Change is that it’s not really a debt that we can leave to younger generations indefinitely. We are not talking about a lake that needs to be cleaned so that our grandchildren can swim in it. If we don’t clean the lake, my kids won’t be as happy, but their livelihood is not at stake.

Climate Change is happening now, so we need solutions that are not minded towards generational equity, but towards saving our entire species. The good thing is that the opportunity cost argument is actually quite useful. The opportunity cost of not having a planet to live on is incalculable. There is no other option. So whatever the cost of reducing GHG in the atmosphere, it’s worth it.

Another point many Green Economists make, and industrial lobbyists seem to ignore, is that Green production can, does and will, create jobs. We will get back to this later. But keep in mind that cleaning the earth does not have to be done at the cost of our incomes and livelihoods. Using the PPF model, one can argue that shifting the economy out of oil production, for example, does not necessarily imply a reduction of economic activity, but rather a shift from one industry to another.

Democracy Booster

World-wide surveys are clear. People want an end to Global Warming. Whether it’s floods or hurricanes, or incredible heat waves, humans have already had enough of the consequences. So why are politicians not on board? It’s a complicated question. But the main reason is that some countries benefit from producing oil, like Canada and the United States of America. Most other countries are poor, and geographically more vulnerable to Climate Change. In essence, the South does not have the power to force the North to change.

Giving a louder voice to those who have the most to lose is the most economically rational thing to do. This is what economists usually argue in favour of. In a conflict, the winning hand should be given to the party who has the most to lose, whose opportunity cost is the greatest. In other words, let the guys who don’t have many choices get a break.

Of course, that is probably not going to happen.

Another solution would be to tie trade agreements to GHG-reduction agreements. Countries who refuse to reduce their GHG emissions will see their export production banned, taxed, or curtailed by quotas, by the countries who suffer the most. We can get back to this solution later when we discuss international trade.

- Wrap-Up

The price of resources needed to provide a good or service does influence the cost of production. When you transform resources and sell for a higher price, you add value.

Economists insist that the true cost of a product must also include the forgone possibility of consuming something else. This is the cost of lost opportunity.

The opportunity cost can be modelled on the Production Possibility Frontier, which helps to illustrate that variety leads to an optimal level of production.

- Cheat Sheet

Added Value:
Buyers are willing to pay more for transformed products that are more useful. Producers can charge more because that transformation incurs added costs.

Opportunity Cost:       
The next best alternative sacrificed when making a choice.

PPF:                            
A curve that represents the maximum production of an economy. The slope of the curve represents the opportunity cost of producing one more unit of Good B.

Division of labour:        Assigning specific tasks to workers according to their strengths.

- References and Further Reading

Fagan, M. & Huang, C. (2019). A look at how people around the world view climate change. Pew Research Center. https://www.pewresearch.org/fact-tank/2019/04/18/a-look-at-how-people-around-the-world-view-climate-change/

Haberler, G. (1930). Die Theorie der komparativen Kosten und ihre Auswertung für die Begründung des Freihandels. In Selected Essays of Gottfried Haberler, volume 32, p. 3 - 19.

Lerner, A. (Aug., 1932). The Diagrammatical Representation of Cost Conditions in International Trade. Economica. No. 37, pp. 346-356.

Pimonenko T., & Chygryn O. (2019) Approaches to Define Environmental Debt in the Framework of Sustainable Development. In: Leal Filho W., Azul A., Brandli L., Özuyar P., Wall T. (eds) Responsible Consumption and Production. Encyclopedia of the UN Sustainable Development Goals. Springer. 

Stolper, W. F., & Samuelson, P. A. (1941). Protection and Real Wages. The Review of Economic Studies. Vol. 9, No. 1, pp. 58-73

von Wieser, F. (1914). Theorie der gesellschaftlichen Wirtschaft (Theory of Social Economy).

Drop this name to impress.


The Austrian economist Friedrich von Wieser coined the term ‘opportunity cost’